Wednesday, April 26, 2006
The Real Friends and Enemies of Wage Earners: An Intellectual
Challenge to the Left
The
reaction to my article on the
United Automobile Workers and GM , confirms how many people—namely, "liberals," "moderates,"
socialists, communists, syndicalists, "mutualists"
and others—believe that businessmen and capitalists
are the enemy, and labor unions and labor
legislation, the friend, of wage earners. This is an
enormous error, with devastating consequences. The
integration of Austrian and Classical economics
carried out in Chapters 11 and 14 of my book
Capitalism: A
Treatise on Economics proves the exact
opposite of this belief. It proves that businessmen
and capitalists are the friend, and labor unions and
labor legislation, the enemy, of wage earners.
Here, in briefest essence, is how.
The
greater is the respect for the property rights and
economic freedom of businessmen and capitalists, the
greater is the degree of saving in the economic
system and thus the higher is the demand for labor
relative to the demand for consumers’ goods and thus
the higher are wages relative to profits. At the
same time, the greater is the demand for capital
goods relative to the demand for consumers’ goods,
and the greater are the incentives to develop and
introduce improved products and methods of
production. The result of this combination is
continuing capital accumulation and a rising
productivity of labor.
The
effect of the progressive rise in the productivity
of labor achieved under capitalism is a
progressively increasing supply of consumers’ goods
relative to the supply of labor and thus
progressively falling prices of consumers’ goods
relative to wage rates. (In the face of an
increasing quantity of money and rising monetary
demand for both labor and consumers’ goods, the
result is wages rising faster than prices. Either
way, the result is rising real wages.)
The
rise in real wages, the result of the saving and
innovation of businessmen and capitalists, and of
wage earners who become businessmen and capitalists,
is a growing ability of wage earners to afford to
work shorter hours, and to dispense with the labor
of their children, and also increasingly to afford
improvements in working conditions of the kind that
do not pay for themselves through increased
productive efficiency. In this way, the saving and
innovation of businessmen and capitalists are what
are in fact responsible for all of the improvements
in the conditions of wage earners typically, and
utterly mistakenly, attributed to labor unions and
labor legislation.
Labor unions do not even know how to raise real
wages. All they are concerned with is raising the
money wages and protecting the jobs of the members
of their particular union. Since labor unions do not
control the quantity of money or volume of spending
in the economic system, the only way that they can
raise the money wages of their members is by
artificially reducing the supply of labor in their
field. But the effect of this is to correspondingly
increase the supply of labor and reduce wage rates
in other fields. In other words the success of any
given union is obtained at the expense of the loss
of wage earners in the rest of the economic system.
And the losses necessarily outweigh the gains,
because an essential aspect of the process is
workers being forced into jobs requiring less skill
and ability than the jobs from which they are
expelled.
If
the unions, or the unions plus minimum-wage laws,
succeed in raising wage rates throughout the
economic system, the effect is corresponding
unemployment in the economic system,
as
well as higher prices because of higher costs and
reduced production. If the unions can succeed in
having the government and its central bank increase
the quantity of money in pace with their wage
demands, the unemployment may be avoided but the
effect is still rising prices along with the rising
wages, and no rise in real wages. Moreover, the
undermining of capital accumulation that results
from the policy of inflation serves to reduce and,
if great enough, reverse the rise in the
productivity of labor and real wages.
The
efforts of unions to protect the jobs of their
members is a policy of actively combating the rise
in real wages of workers throughout the rest of the
economic system. As should be clear from what has
already been said, the way real wages rise is not
from the side of the average worker earning more
money. Earning more money is the result merely of
the increase in the quantity of money, or of the
reduction in the supply of labor available in the
market by forcing part of it into unemployment.
Real
wages rise as the result of capital accumulation and
the rise in the productivity of labor, which
operates to make prices fall relative to wage rates.
In combating the rise in the productivity of labor,
unions actively combat the rise in real wages. Thus,
for example, when the printing unions opposed
computerized typesetting, and thus the resulting
lower costs and lower prices of printed matter, they
were combating the rise in real wages of workers
throughout the economic system who otherwise would
have obtained printed matter for less money and had
correspondingly more money to spare for other things
(which workers displaced from printing could have
helped to produce). Identically the same thing is
true any time any union opposes labor saving
improvements: both the buying power of wage earners
throughout the economic system and the supply of
goods for them to buy are held down.
Yes,
a union may behave this way out of fear of the
difficulties its workers will have in finding new
jobs. But those difficulties would be far less if
money wage rates in the economic system were lower
and thus the quantity of labor demanded were
greater. And what would make that possible is the
absence of coercively imposed union pay-scales and
of minimum wage laws.
Yes,
there are times when employers treat their employees
disrespectfully, indeed, may even treat them as
essentially valueless. But what causes such
conditions is an excess of the supply of labor
available over the quantity of labor demanded. In
such conditions an employer need not fear the loss
of an employee because he can be immediately
replaced from the ranks of the unemployed, and the
employee will be ready to accept abuse out of fear
that he will not be able to find another job.
But
what causes this situation is wage rates held too
high relative to the demand for labor. It arises
under a system of fractional reserve banking, when
credit expansion is followed by financial
contraction and wage rates have not yet fallen to
the point required by the contraction. Let wages
rates fall and the quantity of labor demanded
increase to equal the supply available. At that
point, the scarcity of labor will be felt and the
employee will cease to be instantly replaceable from
the ranks of the unemployed. Plus, he will be able
to find other jobs, and thus not be prepared to
accept abuse. The solution is again a free market.
And ironically, to the extent that labor unions and
minimum wage laws prevent the adjustment of wage
rates to the demand for labor and thus the market’s
natural achievement of essentially full employment,
they are responsible for the bad treatment of
workers that their supporters complain of. (Be sure
to watch for the mirror image of the phenomenon of
someone being treated as valueless, the next time
price controls are imposed on gasoline. Then, as in
the early ’seventies, there will be a shortage of
gasoline and surplus of customers, who will appear
to be economically valueless because instantaneously
replaceable from a waiting line, and ready to accept
abuse because of no where else to go to be
supplied.)
The
fall in wage rates needed to eliminate unemployment
serves to increase production at the same time that
it reduces the costs of production. It thus serves
to bring down prices. It also eliminates the burden
of supporting the unemployed. As a result, it is
almost certain that it soon results in a rise in
real take-home wages.
There are people who produce so little per hour that
they must work many hours to provide for their
minimum necessities, and even use the labor of their
children as a source of additional earnings. It is
of no more help to such people to compel them to
work less, and to do without the labor of their
children, than it would be to compel Robinson Crusoe
to work less or Swiss Family Robinson to work less
and to do without the labor of its children. Crusoe
and the Robinson family do the work they do because
that is what they need to do to live. Compelling
them to work less is to compel poor people to be
poorer than they need to be. It is the same in the
conditions of society. It is no consolation that
those who cause the greater poverty of the poor say
that they have good intentions and want to help.
They cause harm and need to learn to stop.
As
shown, what actually reduced the working day and
abolished child labor was not destructive state
interference but the dramatic and progressive rise
in the productivity of labor brought about by
businessmen and capitalists. That raised real wages
and made it possible for more and more workers to be
able to afford to accept the comparatively lower
earnings of jobs with shorter hours and to eliminate
the need to send their children to work. As a
growing proportion of wage earners came to prefer
shorter hours, the effect was the same as a growing
proportion of workers coming to prefer any one set
of occupations over another, namely, a fall in the
wages of the preferred occupations relative to the
wages in the occupations not preferred. Thus, the
wages of jobs with shorter hours incur a discount,
while the wages of jobs with longer hours gain a
premium. This makes it profitable for employers to
shorten the hours of work. This is how the free
market shortens hours.
My
challenge to the left is to read and study these
ideas at length and in depth in my book
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics, Chapters 11 and 14 in particular. I say to the left, take the
risk of giving up the fallacies you presently regard
as knowledge, in order to gain the satisfaction of
having actual knowledge. Stop supporting the enemies
of economic progress and the harm they do to wage
earners and give your support to the actual friends
of economic progress and of wage earners. The
transformation of you leftist intellectuals into
advocates of capitalism would actually help greatly
to change the direction of the world and, if it is
the overcoming of poverty that you want, move it in
the direction in which you say you want it to go.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Friday, April 21, 2006
Graphic Artistry
One
of the pleasures of writing a Daily Article for the
Mises Institute is the satisfaction of having one’s
article accompanied by a well-chosen graphic.
However, none of my previous experiences of this
kind could have prepared me for the absolutely
brilliant graphic that accompanied my most recent
article
“Where Would General Motors Be Without the United
Automobile Worker’s Union?” This is a graphic
that deserves the kind of commentary usually
reserved for paintings, and in fact is more
deserving of commentary than are most paintings.

Consider the starting point of the graphic: the
actual logo of the UAW (whose use was suggested by
Jeffrey Tucker). Contrary to the intent of those who
created that logo (but true to its actual meaning),
its presence in conjunction with my article depicts
a collection of goons linked arm to arm, in a
mindless circle.
The
artist—Chad Parish of the Mises Institute—has taken
a liberty, however.
He’s
had several of the goons detach themselves from
their mindless circle to go and do some good
old-fashioned union dirty work—the kind of work they
do best. (Some might say that it’s the only kind of
work they do. But that would be an exaggeration.)
Using nothing but GM’s logo, as representing the
whole actual company, he shows the goons busy at the
work of destroying the company. This is communicated
by their act of tearing down the logo, which looks
as if it’s ready to fall. One goon is on the ground,
pulling on the logo with a rope that is hooked
around its top, and another is standing on top of
it, in a triumphant posture, holding what looks like
a rifle; or perhaps it’s only a club. A third goon
is just completing his graffiti message announcing
“UAW WUZ HERE” Two other goons seem to have no
function. Perhaps they are included in deference to
the UAW’s insistence on the employment of
unnecessary workers, represented here by the
employment even of unnecessary goons.
In every way, down to its misspelling of the
graffiti, this graphic is an incredible visual
depiction of the mentality that has decimated or
destroyed one American industry after another and is
now on the verge of destroying what was once the
leading manufacturing corporation in the United
States and in the world.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Wednesday, April 19, 2006
Where Would General Motors Be
Without the United Automobile Workers Union?
This
is a question that no one seems to be asking. And so
I’ve asked it. And here, in essence, is what I think
is the answer. (The answer, of course, applies to
Ford and Chrysler, as well as to General Motors.
I’ve singled out General Motors because it’s still
the largest of the three and its problems are the
most pronounced.)
1.
The company would be without so-called
Monday-morning automobiles. That is, automobiles
poorly made for no other reason than because they
happened to be made on a day when too few workers
showed up, or too few showed up sober, to do the
jobs they were paid to do. Without the UAW, General
Motors would simply have fired such workers and
replaced them with ones who would do the jobs they
were paid to do. And so, without the UAW, GM would
have produced more reliable, higher quality cars,
had a better reputation for quality, and
correspondingly greater sales volume to go with it.
Why didn’t they do this? Because with the UAW, such
action by GM would merely have provoked work
stoppages and strikes, with no prospect that the UAW
would be displaced or that anything would be better
after the strikes. Federal Law, specifically, The
National Labor Relations Act of 1935, long ago made
it illegal for companies simply to get rid of
unions.
2.
Without the UAW, GM would have been free to produce
in the most-efficient, lowest cost way and to
introduce improvements in efficiency as rapidly as
possible. Sometimes this would have meant simply
having one or two workers on the spot do a variety
of simple jobs that needed doing, without having to
call in half a dozen different workers each
belonging to a different union job classification
and having to pay that much more to get the job
done. At other times, it would have meant just going
ahead and introducing an advance, such as the use of
robots, without protracted negotiations with the UAW
resulting in the need to create phony jobs for
workers to do (and to be paid for doing) that were
simply not necessary.
(Unbelievably, at its assembly plant in Oklahoma
City, GM is actually obliged by its UAW contract to
pay 2,300 workers full salary and benefits for doing
absolutely
nothing.
As The New York Times
describes it, “Each day, workers report for duty at the plant and
pass their time reading, watching television,
playing dominoes or chatting. Since G.M. shut down
production there last month, these workers have
entered the Jobs Bank, industry's best form of job
insurance. It pays idled workers a full salary and
benefits even when there is no work for them to
do.”)
3.
Without the UAW, GM would have an average unit cost
per automobile close to that of non-union Toyota.
Toyota makes a profit of about $2,000 per vehicle,
while GM suffers a loss of about $1,200 per vehicle,
a difference of $3,200 per unit. And the far greater
part of that difference is the result of nothing but
GM’s being forced to deal with the UAW. (Over a year
ago,
The Cincinnati Enquirer reported that “the United Auto Workers contract costs GM $2,500
for each car sold.”
4.
Without the UAW, the cost of employing a GM factory
worker, including wages and fringes, would not be in
excess of $72 per hour, which is where it is today,
according to
The Post-Crescent newspaper of Appleton, Wisconsin.
5.
As a result of UAW coercion and extortion, GM has
lost billions upon billions of dollars. For 2005
alone, it reported a loss in excess of $10 billion.
Its bonds are now rated as “junk,” that is, below,
investment grade. Without the UAW, GM would not have
lost these billions.
6.
Without the UAW, GM would not now be in process of
attempting to pay a ransom to its UAW workers of up
to $140,000 per man, just to get them to quit and
take their hands out of its pockets. (It believes
that $140,000 is less than what they will steal if
they remain.)
7.
Without the UAW, GM would not now have healthcare
obligations that account for more than $1,600 of the
cost of every vehicle it produces.
8.
Without the UAW, GM would not now have pension
obligations which, if entered on its balance sheet
in accordance with the rule now being proposed by
the Financial Accounting Standards Board, will leave
it with a net worth of
minus $16 billion.
What
the UAW has done, on the foundation of coercive,
interventionist labor legislation, is bring a
once-great company to its knees. It has done this by
a process of forcing one obligation after another
upon the company, while at the same time, through
its work rules, featherbedding practices, hostility
to labor-saving advances, and outlandish pay scales,
doing practically everything in its power to make it
impossible for the company to meet those
obligations.
9.
Without the UAW tens of thousands of workers—its own
members—would not now be faced with the loss of
pension and healthcare benefits that it is
impossible for GM or any of the other auto companies
to provide, and never was possible for them to
provide. The UAW, the whole labor-union movement,
and the left-“liberal” intellectual establishment,
which is their father and mother, are responsible
for foisting on the public and on the average
working man and woman a fantasy land of imaginary
Demons (big business and the rich) and of saintly
Good Fairies (politicians, government officials, and
union leaders). In this fantasy-land, the Good
Fairies supposedly have the power to wring unlimited
free benefits from the Demons.
Without the UAW and its fantasy-land mentality,
autoworkers would have been motivated to save out of
wages actually paid to them, and to provide for
their future by means of by and large reasonable
investments of those savings— investments with some
measure of diversification. Instead, like small
children, lured by the prospect of free candy from a
stranger, they have been led to a very bad end. They
thought they would receive endless free golden eggs
from a goose they were doing everything possible to
maim and finally kill, and now they’re about to
learn that the eggs just aren’t there.
It’s
very sad to watch an innocent human being suffer.
It’s dreadful to contemplate anyone’s life being
ruined. It’s dreadful to contemplate even an
imbecile’s falling off a cliff or down a well. But
the union members, their union leaders, the
politicians who catered to them, the journalists,
the writers, and the professors who provided the
intellectual and cultural environment in which this
calamity could take place—none of them were
imbeciles. They all could have and should have known
better.
What
is happening is cruel
justice,
imposed by a reality that willfully ignorant people
thought they could choose to ignore as long as it
suited them: the reality that prosperity comes from
the making of goods, not the making of work; that it
comes from the doing of work, not from the shirking
of it; that it comes from machines and methods of
production that save labor, not the combating of
those machines and methods; that it comes from the
earning and reinvestment of profits not from seizure
of those profits for the benefit of idlers, who do
all they can to prevent the profits from being
earned in the first place.
10.
In sum, without the UAW, General Motors would not be
faced with extinction. Instead, it would almost
certainly be a vastly larger, far more prosperous
company, producing more and better motor vehicles
than ever before, at far lower costs of production
and prices than it does today, and providing
employment to hundreds of thousands more workers
than it does today.
Few
things are more obvious than that the role of the
UAW in relation to General Motors has been that of
a swarm of
bloodsucking leeches, a swarm that will
not stop until its prey exists no more.
It
is difficult to believe that people who have been
neither lobotomized nor castrated would not rise up
and demand that these leeches finally be
pulled off!
Perhaps the American people do not rise up, because
they have never seen General Motors, or any other
major American business, rise up and dare to assert
the
philosophical principle of private property rights
and individual freedom and proceed to
pull the leeches off in the name of that principle.
It
is easy to say, and also largely true, that General
Motors and American business in general have not
behaved in this way for several generations because
they no longer have any principles. Indeed, they
would project contempt at the very thought of acting
on any kind of moral or political principle.
One
of the ugliest consequences of the loss of economic
freedom and respect for property rights is that it
makes such spinelessness and gutlessness on the part
of businessmen—such
amorality—a
requirement of succeeding in business.
Business today is conducted in the face of all
pervasive government economic intervention. There is
rampant arbitrary and often unintelligible
legislation. There are dozens of regulatory agencies
that combine the functions of judge, jury, and
prosecutor in the enforcement of more than
75,000
pages of Federal regulations alone. The tax
code is arbitrary and frequently unintelligible.
Judicial protection of economic freedom has not
existed since 1937, when the Supreme Court abandoned
it, out of fear of being enlarged by Congress with
new members sufficient to give a majority to the New
Deal on all issues. (Try to project the effect of a
loss of judicial protection of the freedoms of press
and speech on the nature of what would be published
and spoken.)
Any
business firm today that tried to make a principled
stand on such a matter as throwing out a legally
recognized labor union would have to do so in the
knowledge that its action was a futile gesture that
would serve only to cost it dearly. And a
corporation that did this would undoubtedly also be
embroiled in endless lawsuits by many of its own
stockholders blaming it for the losses the
government imposed on it.
But
none of this should stop anyone else from speaking
up and making known his outrage at what the UAW has
done to General Motors.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Thursday, April 13, 2006
The Actual Nature of Offshoring and of
Our Balance of Trade Deficits
Few
issues are more frequently commented on than the
shifting of American manufacturing to locations
outsides the United States, in order to take
advantage of lower foreign wage rates, particularly
in Asia. This shifting is what is meant by
“offshoring.” With equal or greater frequency
lamentations are heard concerning the United States’
chronic excess of imports over exports, i.e., its
so-called “unfavorable” balance of trade.
Here’s an example that will help to put both matters
in proper perspective.
Assume that an American firm is contemplating the
investment of $10 million of capital, to build a
factory. Construction materials and the use of
construction equipment, along with the machinery to
be installed in the factory, will cost $5 million of
those $10 million. The remaining $5 million will
have to be paid to cover the wages and benefits of
100 American construction workers for a year, at the
rate of $50,000 per man.
In
an impoverished country in Asia, however, the cost
of equally capable construction workers is only
$1,000 per man. In other words, a total labor cost
of $100 thousand, instead of $5 million. The
construction materials, construction equipment, and
the machinery for the factory can all be shipped
there. To make it simple, let’s ignore the costs of
transportation and any other costs associated with
set up abroad. Thus, the total cost of constructing
the plant in Asia would be just $5.1 million,
instead of $10 million. This, of course, is a
powerful incentive for building the plant in Asia.
And, then, once the plant is built, whatever the
number of workers it needs for its operation can be
found locally at a comparably small fraction of the
cost of employing American workers.
Exactly such considerations explain why a very
substantial amount of American manufacturing has
moved offshore. It’s just so much cheaper.
Commentators, who are almost invariably critics, see
this movement of capital offshore. But strangely,
what they do not see is that the process is much
more than just a movement of a given amount of
capital from one place to another. That much, or,
better, that little, is true in terms of monetary
value, but in terms of actual physical wealth, and,
in this case, physical capital, there is a
substantial
increase. Being able to obtain for $5.1
million what one would otherwise need to spend $10
million for, makes it possible to buy practically
twice as much for the same $10 million. Our firm can
build practically
two
factories in Asia for the price of one in the United
States.
An
American firm which invested in this way, would be
in a position to supply its customers with
approximately double the output for the same money,
because it conducted its manufacturing operations in
Asia rather than in the US. Even if it were the
case, as is so often claimed, that displaced
American factory workers must end up as mere
hamburger flippers, the American economic system
would still have this doubled output; plus it would
have all the extra hamburgers the displaced factory
workers would produce.
This
sounds to me like quite an overall gain to the
American economic system.
In
the nature of the case, the gain enters the American
economy in the form of
imports.
In essence, we’re getting the output of two
factories in Asia instead of one in the United
States, and the doubled output is coming into our
economy in the form of imports. Absurdly, this gain
in our wealth is what is called “unfavorable.” It’s
certainly not unfavorable to American consumers. The
only thing I can imagine that would be more
favorable and, at the same time, would be ignorantly
denounced as more unfavorable, would be imports
simply washing up on our shores for free, but
recorded by the customs bureau as having substantial
value.
Offshoring has not resulted in a decline in the
American economic system but just the opposite. It’s
provided the American people with access to vastly
increased manufacturing capacity, which is providing
much larger quantities of goods at sharply lower
prices. And this last is despite substantial
inflation of the American money supply.
Thanks to offshoring, we are supplied with shoes and
clothing, television sets, computers, CD and DVD
players, microwave ovens, and many other goods in
unprecedented quantities and at extremely low
prices. In the nature of the case, this abundance
comes to us in the form of imports.
What
is
the economic problem in this?
I
say, “economic” problem, because I can imagine
something arising that could cause a problem. That
would be the
loss of the offshore factories and the
imports they provide, say, as the result of seizure
by foreign governments and the inept, chaotic
management the governments would impose. That would
be a catastrophe.
But
it cannot be stressed too strongly, the problem is
not in offshoring or in imports; the problem is in
anything that would
threaten
offshoring and the imports it provides.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Monday, April 10, 2006
Immigration Plus Welfare State Equal Police State
Illegal immigrants are overwhelming the resources of
the Welfare State: government–funded hospital
emergency rooms are filled with them; public schools
are filled with their children. On the basis of such
complaints, many people are angry and want to close
the border to new illegal immigrants and deport
those who are already here.
They want to keep new illegal immigrants out with
fences along the border. It is not clear whether the
fences would contain intermittent watchtowers with
searchlights and machine guns. The illegal
immigrants who are already here would be ferreted
out by threatening anyone who employed them with
severe penalties and making it a criminal offense
not to report them.
This is a classic illustration of Mises’s principle
that prior government intervention into the economic
system breeds later intervention. Here the
application of his principle is, start with the
Welfare State, end with the Police State. A police
state is what is required effectively to stop
substantial illegal immigration that has become a
major burden because of the Welfare State.
The philosophy of individual rights and capitalism
implies that
foreigners have a right to come and to live and work
here, i.e., to immigrate into the United States. The
land of the United States is owned by individuals
and voluntary associations of individuals, such as
private business firms. It is not owned by the
United States government or by the American people
acting as a collective; indeed many of the owners of
land in the United States are not Americans, but
foreign nationals, including foreign investors.
The private owners of land have the right to use or
sell or rent their land for any peaceful purpose.
This includes employing immigrants and selling them
food and clothing and all other goods, and selling
or renting housing to them. If individual private
landowners are willing to accept the presence of
immigrants on their property as employees,
customers, or tenants, that should be all that is
required for the immigrants to be present. Anyone
else who attempts to determine the presence of
absence of immigrants is simply an interfering
busybody ready to use a gun or club to impose his
will.
At the same time, however, the philosophy of
individual rights and capitalism implies that the
immigrants do not have a right to be supported at
public expense, which is a violation of the rights
of the taxpayers. Of course, it is no less a
violation of the rights of the taxpayers when
native-born individuals are supported at public
expense. The immigrants are singled out for
criticism based on the allegation that they in
particular are making the burden intolerable.
The implementation of the rights both of the
immigrants and of the taxpayers requires the
abolition of the Welfare State. Ending the Welfare
State will end any problem of immigrants being a
public burden.
Of course, ending the Welfare State is much easier
said than done, and it is almost certainly not going
to be eliminated even in order to avoid the
environment of a police state.
But the burdens of the Welfare State and the
consequent resentment against immigrants could at
the very least be substantially reduced by means of
some relatively simple, common-sense reforms in the
direction of greater economic freedom.
In a future posting, I’ll explain how not only the
problem of chronically crowded hospital emergency
rooms but also the whole so-called crisis of the
medically uninsured, which certainly applies to all
illegal immigrants, could be radically reduced, if
not entirely eliminated, by introducing some simple
economic freedoms into medical care.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Wednesday, April 05, 2006
First, Witchcraft Trials; Now, Impending Health Insurance Fiasco:
Massachusetts Leads the Way
Having just read today’s
New York Times’
lead page-one article titled
“Massachusetts Sets Health Plan for Nearly All,” I think I know what it must be like to live in some place like
Caracas and participate in a popular celebration of
the joyous wonders wrought by
La Revolución.
That’s certainly the spirit of the article.
It
claims in essence to describe how the Governor and
Legislature of Massachusetts have managed to make
medical insurance both available and affordable for
nearly all, at hardly any cost. “The bill,”
The Times’
reporter breathlessly gushes,
does what health experts say no other state has been able to do:
provide a mechanism for all of its citizens to
obtain health insurance. It accomplishes that in a
way that experts say combines methods and proposals
from across the political spectrum, apportioning the
cost among businesses, individuals and the
government.
The
Times
did
not print a copy of the bill, and so I have not read
it. But judging from the article, I’m sure it must
be one incredible mishmash of contradictions,
deceptions, and distortions that are going to cost
the people of Massachusetts dearly. The bill is
openly touted, in effect, as being all things to all
men. An alleged expert is quoted as saying, “`For a
conservative Republican, this is individual
responsibility. For a Democrat, this is government
helping those that need help.’” So the bill
simultaneously satisfies those who supposedly want
to keep the government out of our wallets and those
who eagerly want to let it in, those who want it to
take less from us and those who want it to take more
from us. (Guess which side will win, when the
government is assigned a new and additional task—in
this case, being sure that almost everyone has
health insurance.)
If
that were not enough, the article actually talks of
part of the cost of the bill being
apportioned to the
government. That’s what allegedly helps
to make the bill so affordable: the
government
will pay part of its cost. The article’s actual
words, which bear repeating, are “apportioning the
cost among businesses, individuals and the
government.” This treats the government as some kind
of rich fairy godmother, who is helping to take care
of her people. And to be sure that this claim is not
lost, the print edition of
The Times
brazenly states this fable in a callout set in
large, bold type: “A health care plan paid for by
businesses, individuals and the government.” One of
the surprises apparently in store for many people in
Massachusetts is going to be learning that whatever
is paid for by their government is going to be paid
for by them.
The
article makes clear that those who have not
purchased medical insurance, because they think it’s
too expensive, but who are nevertheless deemed
capable of “affording” it, are going to have it
rammed down their throats. It will be illegal not
have medical insurance.
But never mind. The bill is not always so nasty. It
treads relatively lightly on businesses. “Businesses
with more than 10 workers that do not provide
insurance will be assessed up to $295 per employee
per year.” This is probably enough to cover the cost
of first-class insurance for aspirin tablets and
band aids. The difference between this and any
serious medical insurance will either be paid for by
the taxpayers of Massachusetts or it will turn out
that the whole bill is just a band aid.
There is, however, a bright spot in this bill. And
that is, that if it is enacted, as is virtually
certain, it will be in the state that is the locale
of a major portion of the leftwing intellectual
establishment. So, to that extent, it really
couldn’t happen to a more deserving bunch of people.
But, unfortunately, there are many, many more people
in Massachusetts who do not deserve such legislation
and who will suffer as the result of it.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.
Saturday, April 01, 2006
They Still Don’t Know What They’re Doing, But They Want to Do It
at the Point of a Gun
Here’s a message from an environmentalist who hides under the
name “Tokyo Tom.” He says it comes “off of the web
page of the world-renowned Wood`s Hole Oceanographic
Institute”:
[W]orld leaders may be planning for climate scenarios of global
warming that are opposite to what might actually
occur.
It is important to clarify that we are not
contemplating a situation of either abrupt cooling
or global warming. Rather, abrupt regional cooling
and gradual global warming can unfold
simultaneously. Indeed, greenhouse warming is a
destabilizing factor that makes abrupt climate
change more probable.
What this means is that “world leaders”
simultaneously want to deprive people of the fossil
fuels needed to keep them warm, in the name of
combating global warming, while subjecting them to
freezing cold. They call that government “planning.”
Well, I guess they’re right: it’s par for government
“planning.”
I point out such problems and say that “Economic
freedom is what is required to cope with global
warming, global freezing, or any other form of
large-scale environmental or social change.” And I
explain precisely how it would do so. (See my recent
post
“Collectivism, Climate Change, and Economic
Freedom.”) But when I explain how a free market
would solve such problems, I’m accused of simply
denying the existence of global warming and refusing
to face the facts. The truth is the collectivists
don't want to face the fact that the free market is
the solution.
And yes, the environmentalists are collectivists.
They blame and seek to punish the individual for the
cumulative by-products of the actions of all of
mankind, as though the individual and the human race
were one and the same. If such a thing is possible,
they’re a lower, more lunatic form of collectivist
than were the old socialists. The Marxists in Russia
at least claimed to be concerned with building up
the material means of production—hydroelectric
stations, power plants, steel mills, and so forth,
things that if built on a foundation of voluntary
saving and free labor, really do enormously
contribute to human life and well-being. The
environmentalist witch-doctors in contrast want to
compel a massive global sacrifice of means of
production, in the hope that that will improve the
weather. Maybe they don’t really believe in some
kind of “Weather God” whom their forced sacrifice
will placate, but they’re sure behaving as though
they did.
Copyright ©
2006 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.
George
Reisman, Ph.D., is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of
Economics.