Pillars of Mainstream
Macroeconomics Toppled, Says an Article Published in the July Issue of The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
AUBURN, Ala.--(BUSINESS WIRE)--July 28,
2004--Economics professor George Reisman has toppled a major pillar of
mainstream macroeconomics. In the current issue of "The American Journal
of Economics and Sociology" (July 2004, vol. 63, no. 3), in an article
titled, "The Value of `Final Products' Counts Only Itself," Reisman
refutes the claim that the value of final products (consumers' goods) counts
the value of the intermediate products required in their production and the
corollary claim that counting the value of intermediate products constitutes
the error of "double counting."
Reisman
shows that the fact that the value of a loaf of bread equals the value of the
flour required to produce it plus the value added by the baker in its production,
does not entitle one to forget the value added by the baker and view the
value of the bread as counting simply the value of the flour. He shows that
if one keeps in mind that what the value of the loaf of bread equals is the
value of the flour plus the value added by the baker, then the value of the
bread still counts nothing other than the value of the bread, not the value
of the flour.
Reisman
accuses contemporary macroeconomics of a double violation of the laws of
mathematics: namely, arbitrarily ignoring parts of equations (such as the
value added by the baker to the flour) and then adding up equations, or parts
of equations, that, being alternative, mutually exclusive formulations of the
same facts, are not properly subject to addition. Thus, while the value of a
loaf of bread can be formulated alternatively as equal to the value of the
loaf of bread, or to the value of the flour required to produce it plus the
value added by the baker, or to the value of the wheat plus the values added
by both the baker and the miller, it is still, in all three cases, always
equal just to the value of the loaf of bread. The conclusion of contemporary
economics that by means of these formulations the value of the loaf of bread
counts not only its own value but also that of the flour and wheat requires
first illegitimately ignoring the value added by the baker and the values
added both by the baker and miller, and then adding up these three mutually
exclusive equations (or what remains of them).
Reisman
goes on to argue that since the value of final products counts only itself,
the only way to include the value of the intermediate products is to go out
and count them. Failure to do so, he claims, has made the contemporary
concepts of gross domestic product (GDP)
and gross national product (GNP) into concepts much closer to one of net
product than gross product. He concludes with a presentation of his own view
of a proper gross macroeconomic accounting aggregate, much larger than
GDP/GNP,
which he calls Gross National Revenue (GNR) and which is equal essentially to
the sum of all business sales revenues plus wage and salary payments.
While
the implications of Reisman's article are radical, especially for such
matters as the respective roles of saving and consumption in spending and
income formation, as far as pure aggregate economic accounting is concerned,
his concept of Gross National Revenue can easily be related to the
contemporary macroeconomic accounting aggregates. Subtracting aggregate
business costs from sales revenues, for example, reduces GNR to National
Income, i.e., essentially the sum of profits plus wages. Subtracting those
same costs from the productive and consumption expenditures that constitute
GNR reduces these expenditures to the sum of consumption expenditure plus net
investment. Subtracting all such costs except depreciation cost reduces GNR
to
GDP/GNP
and to consumption expenditure plus today's concept of gross investment.
Where Reisman's approach is radical is that it implies that most spending in
the economic system is concealed under the head of investment and is
productive expenditure, not consumption expenditure, and depends on
abstention from consumption, i.e., on saving.
Reisman,
who is Professor of Economics at Pepperdine
University's Graziadio School of Business and
Management in Los Angeles and the author of "Capitalism: A Treatise on
Economics" (Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996), says that acceptance
of his approach would move economics sharply in the direction of the classical
and Austrian schools and much further away from Keynes.
Click here to read
Reisman's
article in pdf format.
Go or Return
to the Essays Menu
Return to Top of Page
|