Monday, April 23, 2007
It’s About Energy, Not Climate
The
environmental movement has been doing its utmost to sabotage energy
production since the 1960s, long before it was able to latch onto the
prospect of global warming. Its opposition to atomic power has nothing
to do with global warming, nor does its opposition to the construction
of dams to provide hydro-electric power. Indeed, if global warming and
the consumption of fossil fuels, which it alleges is the cause of global
warming, were really its concern, it would be a leading advocate of
atomic power and of the construction of new and additional dams to
provide hydro-electric power. Instead, however, the environmental
movement opposes atomic power even more adamantly than it opposes power
derived from fossil fuels, and it also urges the actual tearing down of
existing dams, even though they provide substantial electric power. (On
this last, see, for example, the article in today’s
New York Times
“Climate Change Adds Twist to Debate Over Dams.”)
The only sources of power that the environmental movement is willing to
allow are wind and sunlight. The first is subject to the proviso that
birds are not killed by flying into the propellers of the windmills. The
second makes no allowance for all of the times when sunlight is blocked,
i.e., in cloudy weather and at night, when the sun has gone down.
Environmentalists like to say that there is a third alternative source
of energy: conservation.
“Conservation” as a source of energy is a contradiction in terms. It is
not a source of energy. Its actual meaning is simply using less energy.
It is a source of energy for one use only at the price of deprivation
somewhere else. Moreover, the logic of conservationism is not consistent
with using energy saved in one part of the economic system to expand
energy use in other parts. Those other parts are also supposed to
conserve, i.e., to use less energy rather than more.
The objective of the environmental movement is and always has been
simply the destruction of energy production. Its further goal is the
undoing of the Industrial Revolution and the return of the modern world
to the poverty and misery of the pre-Industrial era.
This goal is not hidden. It is stated openly. In the words of Maurice
Strong, Founder of the UN Eco-summits and Undersecretary General of the
UN: “Isn't the only hope for the planet that the industrialized
civilizations collapse? Isn't it our responsibility to bring [that]
about?” —as quoted in The
Politically Incorrect Guide to Global Warming and Environmentalism
(Washington, D. C.: Regnery Publishing, Inc., 2007), p. 6.
Destruction of industrial civilization, by means of destroying its
foundation in man-made power. That, not the avoidance of global warming,
is what environmentalism seeks.
The question is, are enough people stupid enough to let it succeed and
allow themselves to be destroyed?
This article is copyright © 2007, by George Reisman. Permission is
hereby granted to reproduce and distribute it electronically and in
print, other than as part of a book and provided that mention of the
author’s web site
www.capitalism.net
is included.
(Email notification
is requested.)
All other rights reserved. George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A
Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is Pepperdine University
Professor Emeritus of Economics.
Labels:
destruction of energy production and of industrial civilization,
Environmentalism and impoverishment,
Maurice Strong
Friday, April 20, 2007
No Representation for Taxation
A bill has
passed the House of Representatives giving a seat in Congress to the
nation’s capital, the District of Columbia.
According to
The New York Times,
For
supporters, the House vote was a victory for democracy, potentially
righting a historical wrong and ending a situation of “taxation without
representation” for 600,000 residents of the District of Columbia.
“This vote fulfills a promise of our democracy,” Representative
Nancy Pelosi of California, the House speaker, said in her floor
speech. “It reflects what we stand for at home and preach around the
world.”
Opposition
to the bill appears to be based merely on the fact that the US
Constitution says that “The House of Representatives shall be composed
of members chosen every second year by the people of the several
states.” (Italics added.) Thus, it is argued, since
Washington, D. C. is not a state, it should have no representative.
Fears are also expressed that enactment of the bill into law would open
the way for the various federal territories, such as Puerto Rico and
Guam, to seek representation.
According to The Times,
opponents of the bill say that a better solution “would be a
constitutional amendment or for Washington to be ceded back to Maryland,
so residents could vote for representatives and senators.”
It’s a sad commentary on the state of our Republic that no one seems to
be pointing out that what is involved here is the nature of the proper
relationship between the citizens of a country and its government. The
United States was founded on the principle that individuals possess
unalienable rights that governments are instituted to protect, and that
among these rights is the right to keep the property one has earned.
The principle of “no taxation without representation” applies to the
context in which those who have earned property strive to keep it by
means of securing the subsidiary right to elect, and thus control, the
members of the legislature that can impose taxes on them.
The overwhelming majority of the citizens of Washington, D. C. are
employees of the federal government or their family members, or are
otherwise supported by the federal government. As such,
they are not taxpayers,
but rather the recipients of taxes paid by other people. Whatever taxes
they nominally pay are merely a deduction from the tax proceeds they
have received. All of the income they obtain and keep is from the
proceeds of taxation.
Denial of the right to vote to citizens of Washington, D. C., serves in
some measure to protect the taxpaying citizens of the United States from
the depredations of those who live off their taxes and who would like to
tax them still more.
Of course, the historical reason that Washington, D. C. does not have
representation in Congress was not in order to deprive government
employees of the right to vote. Such protection was not deemed necessary
in an environment in which the only sources of federal revenue were
tariffs and the sale of land. The historical reason was that the federal
government was viewed in important respects as subsidiary to the states
and not as their equal.
Nevertheless, it is certainly a good thing for the rest of the country
that the citizens of Washington, D. C. do not have the vote. It
implicitly serves to support the fundamental principle that the
disposition of an individual’s property should be decided by him, not
jointly by him and thieves who want to rob him.
The possession of the right to vote by government employees and by
anyone else who receives a substantial portion of his wealth or income
from the government is in fact giving legal power to those who receive
the wealth of others to proceed to take that wealth. It is literally
giving the vote to thieves.
That may be Nancy Pelosi’s conception of democracy and of what the
United States stands for. But it is the kind of democracy that is
present in a lynch mob. And what the United States actually stands for,
and should stand for, is the rights of the individual against the
mob—against the entire rest of the world if need be.
Hopefully, the Senate will prevent the House’s bill from becoming law.
Representation in the House of Representatives for Washington, D. C. and
its mass of tax recipients would not end a situation of “taxation
without representation.” This is because, as we've seen, the citizens of
Washington, D.C., do not pay taxes; they receive them. All that giving
them representation would do would be to provide additional
representation for advocates of additional taxation and thus further
weaken the power of taxpayers to defend their right to keep their own
property. As such, it would be directly contrary to the principle of no
taxation without representation—that is, of course,
representation for those who have
earned the wealth being taxed, not those who want to tax it.
This article is copyright © 2007, by George Reisman. Permission is
hereby granted to reproduce and distribute it electronically and in
print, other than as part of a book and provided that mention of the
author’s web site
http://www.capitalism.net/ is included.
(Email notification is requested.) All other rights reserved. George
Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on
Economics (Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is
Pepperdine University Professor Emeritus of Economics.
Labels:
No Representation for Taxation,
No Taxation Without Representation
Wednesday, April 18, 2007
Keeping Up With the Party Line at The New York Times/Pravda
From the
movie review
“Casualties of China’s Transformed
Economy”
by Jeannette Catsoulis, in today’s
Times:
Bracketed
by stunning long shots taken from the front of a moving freight train,
Wang Bing’s epic, three-part documentary, “Tie Xi Qu: West of Tracks,”
is an astonishingly intimate record of China’s painful transition from
state-run industry to a free market. Filming between 1999 and 2001, Mr.
Wang and his sound engineer, Lin Xudong, painstakingly document the
death throes of the Tie Xi industrial district in the city of Shenyang,
in northeast China, a once-vibrant symbol of a thriving socialist
economy.
How foolish
of China to abandon its “thriving socialist economy” of perpetual mass
starvation for a rapidly progressing market economy of soaring
skyscrapers and rising living standards for hundreds of millions.
From the book review by William Grimes
“Looking Back in Anger at the
Gilded Age’s Excesses”
in today’s Times:
Again and
again, surveying the post-Civil War landscape, Mr. Beatty throws up his
hands in despair. “The people supported the government, and the
government supported the corporations and the rentiers with the people’s
money,” he writes. “And the people did not seem to object, at least not
enough of them.”
Maybe that’s because of wheeler-dealers like Jay Gould, who once
boasted, “I can hire one half of the working class to kill the other
half.” They just don’t make them like that anymore.
Or maybe
it’s because the reviewer and author (Jack Beatty, a senior editor at
The Atlantic Monthly)
are 180 degrees wrong. Instead of the “robber barons” stealing the
industries that did not exist before they created them, and
impoverishing those who had next to nothing in the first place, the vast
new wealth that the great industrialists employed as capital served
radically and progressively to increase the supply of goods available to
the common man to buy and increased the demand for the labor that he
sold. That’s the actual nature and significance of the fact that, in the
reviewer’s words, “The richest 1 percent owned 26 percent of the wealth,
and the richest 10 percent owned 72 percent.” The hated rich created
that new and additional wealth and were led by the nature of the profit
motive, capital, and free markets to employ it for the progressive
benefit of the masses.
Such is the intellectual and moral state of
The New York Times, a
veritable cesspool of wrong and vicious ideas serving day in and day out
to poison the minds of its readers against the capitalist economic
system and economic freedom.
This article is copyright © 2007, by George Reisman. Permission is
hereby granted to reproduce and distribute it electronically and in
print, other than as part of a book and provided that mention of the
author’s web site
www.capitalism.net
is included.
(Email notification
is requested.)
All other rights reserved. George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A
Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is Pepperdine University
Professor Emeritus of Economics.
Labels:
capital,
capitalist economic system,
economic freedom,
free market,
New York Times,
profit motive,
robber barons
Tuesday, April 17, 2007
An Update to Henry Hazlitt’s “Uruguay: Welfare State Gone Wild”
Back in
1969, Henry Hazlitt’s
Man Versus the Welfare State appeared. It was a valuable
collection of essays, one of which was “Uruguay: Welfare State Gone
Wild.”
This essay consisted largely of a series of verbal “snapshots” of
Uruguay, as Hazlitt called them, in the form of quotations drawn from a
variety of sources over the years 1956 to 1968. What Hazlitt described
by means of the quotations was an economic system plunged into ruin by
unrestrained welfare-state spending.
Having taken a tour of Montevideo, Uruguay’s capital, last month, I’d
like to offer a “snapshot” as of the present year, 2007.
What I saw was a city of almost unrelieved drabness and ruin. Graffiti
filled walls within a hundred yards of the seat of the country’s
Congress. The city’s public parks, presented as an attraction to
tourists, were overgrown with weeds; the wrought-iron fences they
contained were in a state of collapse. Building after building, in
neighborhood after neighborhood, was in a state disrepair. Often, only a
burnt-out concrete shell was left. Hardly anything, anywhere, looked
new. Much of the city was reminiscent of the South Bronx, an area
devastated by more than two generations of rent controls. Only one,
small area of the city, near the River Plate, appeared to be at all
prosperous.
Uruguay no longer has trains. “They don’t work anymore,” our tour-guide
announced. “Uruguay has been resting for the last 50 years and has made
no progress in that time,” she said. The population of Montevideo and of
the country as a whole are both declining. A large proportion of
university graduates in particular leave, in search of better
opportunities elsewhere.
From what I saw, if there are another 50 years of such “rest,” there may
be nothing much left of Montevideo beyond an impoverished village.
Copyright © 2007 by George Reisman.
Labels:
Uruguay an impoverished welfare state
Return to Top of
Page