Saturday, November 25, 2006
Penn and Teller Send Recycling to the Dump
I’ve never
had much use for Penn and Teller, a pair of comedians that I’ve seen
from time to time on television and then have quickly turned off. But
the other day, a reader of my blog, Mr. Robert Groot, a Canadian Ph.D.
student, was kind enough to send me a link to their internet show on
recycling.
I have to say that this show has made me a fan of theirs. It was a
scathing critique of the illogic of recycling, done in a way that at
times was hilarious.
I should add that at least in this show, the pair come across as serious
libertarians, in addition to being powerful critics of recycling.
The first few minutes of the show are a little slow, but within 5
minutes, things pick up. Whatever you do, be sure to watch at least the
first 8 or 9 minutes. (The full length is about half an hour.) There’s a
sequence in there that you may find so funny you’ll have trouble
catching your breath.
Here’s the link:
http://geeksaresexy.blogspot.com/2006/11/recycling-is-grigri-just-plain.html.
Friday, November 17, 2006
Globalization: The Long-Run Big Picture
Summary
Globalization, in conjunction with its essential prerequisite of respect
for private property rights, and thus the existence of substantial
economic freedom in the various individual countries, has the potential
to raise the productivity of labor and living standards all across the
world to the level of the most advanced countries. In addition, it has
the potential to bring about the radical improvement in productivity and
living standards in what are today the most advanced countries, and to
provide the strongest possible foundation for unprecedented further
economic advance everywhere.
These overwhelmingly beneficial results are often hidden from view by
the fact that at the same time globalization implies a substantial
decline in the relative or even absolute nominal GDPs of today's
advanced countries, the experience of which engenders opposition to the
process. What is not seen is that to whatever extent globalization might
reduce absolute nominal GDP in today's advanced countries, it reduces
prices many times more, with the result that it correspondingly
increases their real GDP, and that to whatever extent it reduces merely
their relative nominal GDP, it again increases their real GDP many times
more.
This
article shows that by incorporating billions of additional people into
the global division of labor, and correspondingly increasing the scale
on which all branches of production and economic activity are carried
on, globalization makes possible the unprecedented achievement of
economies of scale—the maximum consistent with the size of the world's
population. First and foremost among these will be the very substantial
increase in the number of highly intelligent, highly motivated
individuals working in all of the branches of science, technology, and
business. This will greatly accelerate the rate of scientific and
technological progress and business innovation. The achievement of all
other economies of scale will also serve to increase what it is possible
to produce with any given quantity of capital goods and labor.
Out
of this larger gross product comes a correspondingly larger supply of
capital goods, which makes possible a further increase in production,
resulting in a still larger supply of capital goods, in a process that
can be repeated indefinitely so long as scientific and technological
progress and business innovation continue and an adequate degree of
saving and provision for the future is maintained. The article shows
that from the very beginning, the process of globalization serves to
promote capital accumulation simply by dramatically increasing
production in the countries in which foreign capital is invested, out of
which increase in production comes an additional supply of capital
goods.
Some critics of globalization, notably Paul Craig Roberts, do not
understand how it promotes capital accumulation and instead believe that
it deprives the advanced countries of capital. Others, notably Gomory
and Baumol, view the effect of globalization on nominal GDP as though it
were its effect on real GDP and are thus led to confuse competition for
limited money revenue and income with economic conflict. This article
answers both sets of errors, including related confusions concerning
outsourcing.
To continue reading, click here.
Thursday, November 16, 2006
Standards of Environmental
Good and Evil: Why Environmentalism Is Misanthropic
It is very
common for people to talk nowadays about environmental good and evil,
but with virtually no explicit statement of the standards by which
something is to be judged environmentally good or evil. People are
unaware that a standard is always present and that there is more than
one such standard. There are in fact two diametrically opposed and
mutually exclusive standards of environmental good and evil. The
following example will bring them out.
Thirty years ago, the land under the house I live in, in Southern
California, was empty desert. Had I wanted to sleep in the same location
that my bedroom now stands on, I would have had to bring a sleeping bag,
take precautions against rattlesnakes, scorpions, and coyotes, and hope
I could find a place for my sleeping bag such that I wouldn’t have rocks
pressing into my body. If it rained, I would get wet. If it was cold, I
would be cold. If it was hot, I would be hot. Going to the bathroom
would be a chore. Washing up would be difficult or impossible.
How incomparably better is the environment provided by my house and my
bedroom. I sleep on a bed with an innerspring mattress. I don’t have to
worry about snakes, scorpions, or coyotes. I’m protected from the rain,
the cold, and the heat, by a well constructed house with central heating
and air conditioning. I have running water, hot and cold, a flush
toilet, a sink, a shower, and a bathtub, in fact more than one of each
of these things, and I have electricity and most of the conveniences it
makes possible, such as a refrigerator, a television set, a VCR, and CD
and DVD players.
It’s obvious to me that the existence of my house constitutes an
enormous improvement in my environment compared with living at the same
location on the bare ground, and that the same is true of the existence
of virtually all houses in relation to the environment of their
occupants. It’s further obvious to me that the process of improving the
environment in this way starts with developers and contractors who bring
in bulldozers and other heavy construction equipment to clear the tops
of hills, level and compact the land, build streets, and utility
connections, and construct houses.
Yet those who are called “environmentalists” describe the exact same
process of development and construction as harming the environment. Why?
Because they have a profoundly different standard of environmental good
and evil than the one that is present in my example. The standard that
is present in my example is that of human life and well-being. What is
environmentally good according to this standard is the promotion of
human life and well-being, notably, housing construction and the
existence of houses. What is environmentally evil is what impairs human
life and well-being, such as preventing housing construction.
The environmentalists call the construction of houses evil because, as I
say, their standard of value is very different. Instead of taking human
life and well-being as their standard of value, they take
nature in and of itself as their standard of value. Nature,
they say, has intrinsic value,
i.e., value in and of itself, apart from all connection with human life
and well-being. Thus, in their view, hillsides and empty land, as they
exist in a state of nature, together with their wildlife, have intrinsic
value. And it is those alleged intrinsic values that are harmed by
development and construction. In other words, the harm the
environmentalists complain about in such cases is harm only from a
non-human, indeed, anti-human
perspective.
Here is a classic statement of the doctrine of intrinsic value by one of
its leading environmentalist supporters:
This [man’s
“remaking the earth by degrees”] makes what is happening no less tragic
for those of us who value wildness for its own sake, not for what value
it confers upon mankind. I, for one, cannot wish upon either my children
or the rest of Earth’s biota a tame planet, be it monstrous or—however
unlikely—benign. McKibben is a biocentrist, and so am I. We are not
interested in the utility of a particular species or free-flowing river,
or ecosystem, to mankind. They have intrinsic value, more value—to
me—than another human body, or a billion of them.
Human happiness, and certainly human fecundity, are not as important as
a wild and healthy planet. I know social scientists who remind me that
people are part of nature, but it isn’t true. Somewhere along the
line—at about a billion years ago, maybe half that—we quit the contract
and became a cancer. We have become a plague upon ourselves and upon the
Earth.
It is cosmically unlikely that the developed world will choose to end
its orgy of fossil-energy consumption, and the Third World its suicidal
consumption of landscape. Until such time as Homo sapiens should decide
to rejoin nature, some of us can only hope for the right virus to come
along. (David M. Graber, in his review of Bill McKibben’s
The End of Nature, in the
Los Angeles Times Book Review,
Sunday, October 22, 1989, p. 9.)
The
doctrine of intrinsic value is present in such statements as the North
Slope of Alaska is “a sacred place” that should never be given over to
oil rigs and pipelines. It is present in such statements as, “There is a
need to protect the land not just for wildlife and human recreation, but
just to have it there.” It is present in all instances in which forests,
rivers, canyons, hillsides, or any other natural formation is presented
as automatically deserving to be preserved, irrespective of its value in
being put to use by human beings. And, of course, it is present in all
the numerous cases in which human life or well-being have been
sacrificed for the sake of the preservation of this or that species of
animal or plant. Such cases range from the sacrifice of the property
rights of human beings for the sake of snail darters and spotted owls,
to the sacrifice of untold millions of actual human lives. This last has
occurred as the result of the resurgence of malaria because the use of
DDT was prohibited in order to preserve the alleged intrinsic value of
some species of birds.
It is crucial that people recognize the distinction between the two
standards of environmental good and evil and that the standard of the
environmental movement is fundamentally that of the intrinsic value of
nature, not that of human life and well-being. Given its standard of
value, it is certainly not possible to accept as sincere or
well-motivated any of the claims the environmental movement makes of
seeking to improve human life and well-being, whether in connection with
its allegations about global warming, the ozone layer, acid rain, or
anything else.
Indeed, environmentalism’s acceptance of the doctrine of intrinsic value
implies a profound hatred of man and a desire to destroy him. Such
statements as those of Mr. Graber, that I quoted above, expressing a
wish for a virus to come along and kill a billion human beings, are not
at all accidental. They are
logically implied by environmentalism’s standard of value.
Acceptance of the doctrine of intrinsic value, as I wrote in
Capitalism, “inexorably
implies a desire to destroy man and his works because it implies a
perception of man as the
systematic destroyer of the good, and thus as the systematic doer of
evil. Just as man perceives coyotes, wolves, and
rattlesnakes as evil because they regularly destroy the cattle and sheep
he values as sources of food and clothing, so, on the premise of
nature’s intrinsic value, the environmentalists view man as evil,
because, in the pursuit of his well-being, man systematically destroys
the wildlife, jungles, and rock formations that the environmentalists
hold to be intrinsically valuable. Indeed, from the perspective of such
alleged intrinsic values of nature, the degree of man’s alleged
destructiveness and evil is directly in proportion to his loyalty to his
essential nature. Man is the rational being. It is his application of
his reason in the form of science, technology, and an industrial
civilization that enables him to act on nature on the enormous scale on
which he now does. Thus, it is his possession and use of
reason—manifested in his technology and industry—for which he is hated.”
(p, 82)
The primitive hunter-gatherers who were modern man’s remote ancestors
left virtually no mark whatever on the rest of nature. The alleged
intrinsic values destroyed in their gathering and eating nuts and
berries and in their hunting, killing, and eating animals were quickly
and automatically replenished by nature. The pre-industrial farmers who
were modern man’s more recent ancestors left an imprint on nature that
was essentially limited to plowed fields and primitive villages. And
though somewhat more enduring, it was still very limited in extent.
Great limitation of extent characterizes the enduring mark left by the
pyramids, the ruins of towns and cities built in antiquity, and the
stone castles of the Middle Ages.
In contrast, the modern man of capitalism clears entire forests and
jungles; he drains swamps and irrigates deserts. He changes the balance
of nature by decimating and destroying entire species of plants and
animals and, though not often mentioned, radically increasing the
populations of others, whose characteristics he alters to suit him. He
establishes mechanized farms, large numbers of major towns and cities,
indeed, giant metropolises. He builds factories, roads, bridges and
tunnels, dams and canals. He digs mines, sometimes moving entire
mountains in doing so, and drills for oil and gas, often reaching depths
of several miles. From the perspective of environmentalism and its
doctrine of intrinsic value, these activities, which leave a large and
enduring mark on a vast swath of the rest of nature, constitute the
destruction of intrinsic values on a massive scale and thus characterize
modern man as the doer of massive evil.
Keeping all this in mind, it follows that it is absolutely perilous for
human beings to allow themselves to be guided by policies recommended by
the environmental movement, especially when doing so would impose great
deprivation or cost, such as would be entailed in having to make radical
reductions in carbon dioxide emissions to combat global warming. Nothing
could be more absurd or dangerous than to take advice on how to improve
one’s life and well-being from those who regard one’s wealth and
happiness as a source of harm, who accord one the status of vermin, and
who wish one dead as the means of preserving nature’s alleged intrinsic
values. Indeed, not only Mr. Graber, but also other prominent
environmentalists have expressed a wish for human deaths on a scale that
far surpasses all those caused by the Nazis and Communists combined.
The danger of accepting environmentalist claims, it must be stressed,
applies irrespective of the scientific or academic credentials of an
individual. If an alleged scientific expert believes in the intrinsic
value of nature, then to seek his advice is equivalent to seeking the
advice of a medical doctor who was on the side of the germs rather than
the patient, if such a thing can be imagined. It is the equivalent of a
Jew asking the medical advice of a Dr. Josef Mengele.
All advice, all policy recommendations emanating from the
environmentalist movement must be summarily rejected unless and until
they can be validated on the basis of a pro-man, pro-wealth,
pro-capitalist standard of value. Such a standard will never imply such
a thing as the destruction of the energy base of industrial civilization
as the means of addressing global warming.
The environmental movement is the philosophic enemy of the human race.
It should be treated as such. If we value the material well-being and,
indeed, the very lives of billions of our children and grandchildren, we
must treat it as such. We must treat environmentalism as our mortal
enemy.
This article is copyright © 2006, by George Reisman. Permission is
hereby granted to reproduce and distribute it electronically and in
print, other than as part of a book and provided that mention of the
author’s web site
www.capitalism.net
is included.
(Email notification
is requested.)
All other rights reserved. George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is Pepperdine University
Professor Emeritus of Economics.
Wednesday, November 08, 2006
Two Ice Ages, With Up to 16 Times the
Carbon Dioxide in the Atmosphere
In the last
500 million years, there have been two ice ages at the same time that
vastly higher carbon dioxide levels prevailed in the earth's atomosphere—up
to 16 times the present level.
This remarkable finding, along with others, was reported in yesterday’s
(November 7, 2006) New York Times.
For details, see the article by William Broad, “In
Ancient Fossils, Seeds of a New Debate on Warming.”
The article contains references to the work of a number of important
scientists who aren’t supposed even to exist, according to the
environmentalist propaganda machine, which brooks no opposition. The
article deserves to be required reading for everyone who is seriously
interested in the subject of global warming.
Tuesday, November 07, 2006
Freedom of Choice in New York City:
Diet, No; Gender, Yes
From
The New York Times
of October 31, 2006:
Dozens of
people appeared before the city’s Board of Health yesterday, offering a
largely favorable response to proposed restaurant regulations that would
ban all but a minute amount of artificial trans fats in food
preparation, and require some restaurants to post calorie counts on
their menus and menu boards.
The board has said it planned to vote on both proposals, which are
supported by Mayor
Michael R. Bloomberg, in December. The hearing yesterday was part of
a process of public comment that also includes written responses.
The New York City proposals, which have drawn attention across the
country, would establish some of the most rigorous limits on trans fats
in restaurants and set requirements for menu labeling more rigid than in
any other American city.
From
The New York Times
of November 7, 2006:
Separating
anatomy from what it means to be a man or a woman, New York City is
moving forward with a plan to let people alter the sex on their birth
certificate even if they have not had sex-change surgery.
Under the rule being considered by the city’s Board of Health, which is
likely to be adopted soon, people born in the city would be able to
change the documented sex on their birth certificates by providing
affidavits from a doctor and a mental health professional laying out why
their patients should be considered members of the opposite sex, and
asserting that their proposed change would be permanent.
Bottom
line: Starting soon, in New York City, you won’t be able to buy a donut
baked with trans fat, but you will be able choose your sex, irrespective
of your anatomy.
If
you think this is crazy, you’d better watch out and not say so. That’s
because sooner or later, if there isn’t already, there will be a further
regulation that bans such dissent as “antisocial,” “insensitive,” or
“offensive.”
Even
so, I can’t suppress the thought that if the hosts of, say, the Boston
Tea Party, were alive, they might physically relocate New York City’s
Board of Health to the streets below, perhaps with its office furniture
wrapped around its members’ necks. A hostile response, I know. But then
I’m feeling like that rattlesnake on a flag of my country’s
Revolutionary War. His message to the world was, “Don’t Tread on Me.”
George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is Pepperdine University
Professor Emeritus of Economics. His web site is
www.capitalism.net.
© 2006, by George Reisman.
Wednesday, November 01, 2006
Britain’s Stern Review on Global
Warming: It Could Be Environmentalism’s Swan Song
To the
accompaniment of much fanfare and hoopla, the British government has
released Sir Nicholas Stern’s
Stern Review on the Economics of
Climate Change,
a report that it commissioned but that it labels “independent.”
The report is a rehash of now standard environmentalist claims
concerning alleged disasters that await the world if it continues with
its wicked ways of fossil fuel consumption: the disappearance of islands
beneath the sea, the flooding of coastal cities, more severe droughts
and hurricanes, famines, disease, the displacement of tens of millions
of people from their traditional homelands—it’s all regurgitated in the
report. A couple of times, however, the report provides a hint of
something even much worse:
Under a BAU
[business as usual] scenario, the stock of greenhouse gases could more
than treble by the end of the century, giving at least a 50% risk of
exceeding 5°C global average temperature change during the following
decades. This would take humans into unknown territory. An illustration
of the scale of such an increase is that we are now only around 5°C
warmer than in the last ice age. (p. ix of the
Executive Summary.)
It remains unclear whether warming could initiate a self-perpetuating
effect that would lead to a much larger temperature rise or even runaway
warming . . . . (p. 10 of the full report, the
Stern Review.)
The
frightening allusions to “unknown territory” and “runaway warming” come
very close to conjuring up old-time religious images of hellfire and
brimstone as the fate of the world if it does not take Sir Nicholas’s
Report to heart and repent of its ways. But Sir Nicholas never actually
does make this threat. He leaves it merely to implication.
Perhaps if it were made, it would be easier for people to identify the
environmentalists’ fears for the empty bugaboo that they are and dismiss
them. Their response would need be only that if economic progress and
the enjoyment of its fruits will consume the world in flames, and thus
that living like human beings means we really will all go to hell, as
the preachers have always claimed, then so be it. Better to live as
human beings now, while we can, than throw it away for the sake of
descendants living as pre-industrial, medieval wretches later on. (But,
of course, we will never have to make such a choice, for reasons that
will become clear shortly.)
Surprisingly, the actual negative consequences Sir Nicholas alleges that
will occur from global warming are extremely tame, at least in
comparison with hellfire. In his “Summary of Conclusions,” he writes:
Using the
results from formal economic models, the Review estimates that if we
don’t act, the overall costs and risks of climate change will be
equivalent to losing at least 5% of global GDP each year, now and
forever. If a wider range of risks and impacts is taken into account,
the estimates of damage could rise to 20% of GDP or more.
Sir Nicholas’s use of the words “don’t act” is very misleading. What he
is urging when he speaks of “action” is a mass of laws and decrees—i.e.,
government action.
This government action will forcibly
prevent hundreds of
millions, indeed, billions of individual human beings from engaging in
their, personal and business
private action—that is, from acting in ways that they judge
to serve their own self-interests. Thus, what he is actually urging is
not action, but government action intended to stop private action.
Furthermore, he does not explain why he believes that global warming
means the end of all subsequent economic progress, though that is
implied in the words “now and forever.” He compares the dangers of
global warming to “those associated with the great wars and the economic
depression of the first half of the 20th century(ibid.),” yet seems to
forget the stupendous economic progress that followed them.
According to Sir Nicholas, what we must do to avoid the loss of up to
20% of annual GDP, is ultimately to reduce our carbon dioxide emissions
“more than 80% below the absolute
level of current annual emissions.” (p. xi of the
Executive Summary. My
italics.) Lest one think that such drastic reduction lies only in the
very remote future, Sir Nicholas also declares,
By 2050,
global emissions would need to be around 25% below current levels. These
cuts will have to be made in the context of a world economy in 2050 that
may be 3 - 4 times larger than today - so emissions per unit of GDP
would need to be just one quarter of current levels by 2050. (Ibid.)
In appraising Sir Nicholas’s views, it should be kept in mind that our
ability to produce, now and for many years to come, vitally depends on
the use of fossil fuels. These fuels are the source of most of our
electric power and thus of our ability to use machinery. They propel our
trucks, trains, ships, and planes. And, of course, their use entails the
emission of carbon dioxide. Thus, it would seem that Sir Nicholas’s
means of preventing even a 20% loss of GDP would entail a far greater
loss of GDP than 20%. It follows that if it is output that concerns us,
we would be better off simply accepting global warming, if that is what
is in store, than attempting to avoid it in the way Sir Nicholas
prescribes. We will certainly not produce 3-4 times the output in 2050
with 25% less carbon dioxide emission. Far more likely, if such a
reduction is forced upon us, we will produce substantially less output,
despite the probable existence of a substantially larger population by
then.
Sir Nicholas appears to be as naïve in his estimate of the cost of
replacing today’s technologies of fuel and power as he is in estimating
the effect of their loss. Without evidence of any kind, he claims that
while the cost of “inaction” is as much as 20% of annual global GDP,
“the costs of action – reducing greenhouse gas emissions to avoid the
worst impacts of climate change – can be limited to around 1% of global
GDP each year.”
Thus his program is designed to appear as really quite a bargain: the
world’s governments will appropriate an additional mere 1% of global GDP
each year in order to prevent their citizens from wantonly destroying as
much as 20% of annual global GDP by foolishly pursuing their own
self-interests. And it turns out that, in Sir Nicholas’s view, even this
1% is far more than is required by the governments for the actual
development of new technologies. In his chapter titled “Accelerating
Technological Innovation,” he writes that “Global public energy R&D
funding should double, to around $20 billion, for the development of a
diverse portfolio of technologies.” (p. 347 of the
Stern Review.) Twenty
billion dollars are a mere
one-twentieth of one percent of the world’s current annual
GDP of roughly $40 trillion. That’s supposed to be all that it takes to
develop the technologies that will enable the world to eventually reduce
carbon emissions by 80% from today’s levels.
How easy and simple it is all supposed to be, if only we will do as we
are told, and get started doing so right away. All we have to do is sit
back and leave the direction of our lives in the hands of the
government. It will solve the problem of changing the global technology
of energy production with the same success that the Soviets and the
British Laborites pursued their respective varieties of socialism and
with the same success that our own government has conducted its wars on
poverty, drugs, and terror, and in Vietnam and Iraq. Did I say,
“success”?
Sir Nicholas’s Review
is characterized by an apparent belief in a kind of magical power of
words to create and control reality. Thus, the actual fact,
as reported in The New York Times,
is that “About one large coal-burning plant is being commissioned a
week, mostly in China.” In the same report,
The Times points out that
“A typical new coal-fired power plant, [is] one of the largest sources
of emissions, [and] is expected to operate for many decades.” Totally
ignoring these facts, Sir Nicholas believes he has said something
meaningful and significant when he writes,
Developing
countries are already taking significant action to decouple their
economic growth from the growth in greenhouse gas emissions. For
example, China has adopted very ambitious domestic goals to reduce
energy used for each unit of GDP by 20% from 2006-2010 and to promote
the use of renewable energy. India has created an Integrated Energy
Policy for the same period that includes measures to expand access to
cleaner energy for poor people and to increase energy efficiency.” (p.
xxiv of Executive Summary.)
To say the least, this represents the use of a mere statements of intent
concerning action in the future in an effort to override the
diametrically opposite character of China’s and India’s actual actions
in the present, and in the foreseeable future as well if these countries
are to achieve further substantial economic development.
Another illustration of the attempt to employ words as though their use
could control reality, occurs in Sir Nicholas’s discussion of “learning
and economies of scale” in connection with low-carbon technologies. He
notes that “The cost of technologies tends to fall over time, because of
learning and economies of scale,” and appears to conclude from this that
low-carbon technologies can therefore eventually be as efficient as the
high-carbon technologies they are supposed to replace when the latter
are forcibly curtailed. He writes, “There have been major advances in
the efficiency of fossil-fuel use; similar progress can also be expected
for low-carbon technologies as the state of knowledge progresses.” (Stern
Review, p. 225.) It apparently does not occur to him that
there may be some necessary order of sequence involved and that the use
of high-carbon technologies is the necessary foundation for the possible
later adoption of low-carbon technologies.
Presumably, he does not believe that in the period 1750-1950,
industrialization could have proceeded on the foundation of low-carbon
technologies. For example, before such technology as that of atomic
power could be developed, generations of industrial progress had to take
place on a foundation of fossil fuels. And this was equally true for the
technology of wind turbines and solar power. The ability to produce the
materials, components, and equipment required by these low-carbon
technologies rests on the existence of previously established highly
developed carbon-based technologies. Further substantial economic
development on the same foundation is required for the further
development of low-carbon technologies.
Wherever the use of high-carbon technology is cheaper than that of
low-carbon technology, forcibly curtailing its use implies the forcible
reduction of the physical volume of production in the economic system,
including its ability to produce further capital goods. Thus, forcibly
curtailing the use of carbon-based technology cuts the ground from
beneath the development of future low-carbon technology. It aborts the
development of the necessary industrial base. (For elaboration of these
points, see my Capitalism, pp. 178-179, 212, 622-642.)
Sir Nicholas’s and the rest of the environmental movement’s hostility to
carbon technology, is ultimately contrary to purpose not only insofar as
it prevents the development of the low-carbon technologies they claim to
favor, but also in that it simultaneously, and more fundamentally,
operates to deprive the world of
the ability to counteract destructive climate change, such as global
warming.
Whether or not they are aware of it, in attempting to combat alleged
global warming, Sir Nicholas, and the rest of the environmentalists, are
urging a policy of deliberate counteractive global climate change by the
world’s governments. They want the world’s governments to change the
world’s climate from the path that they believe it is otherwise destined
to take. They want the world’s governments to make the earth’s climate
cooler than they believe it will otherwise be as the next two centuries
or more unfold. But their policy of climate control is the most stupid
one imaginable. It’s more stupid than a modern-day equivalent of a
savage’s attempting to control nature by the sacrifice of his goat.
The reason it’s more stupid, much more stupid, is that the goat that
they want to sacrifice is most of modern industrial civilization—the
part that depends on the 80% of the carbon emissions they want to
eliminate, and which will not be replaced through any magical power of
words to create and control reality, however much they may believe in
that power. It is precisely modern industrial civilization and its
further expansion and intensification that is mankind’s means of coping
with all aspects of nature, including, if it should ever actually be
necessary, the ability to control the earth’s climate, whether to cool
it down or to warm it up.
If mankind ever really finds it necessary to control the earth’s
climate, whether to prevent global warming or, as is in fact probably
more likely, a new ice age, its ability to do so will depend on the
power of its economic system. An economic system with the ability to
provide such things as massive lasers, fleets of rocket ships carrying
cargoes of various chemicals, equipment, and materials for deployment in
outer space, with the ability to create major chemical reactions here on
earth too, if necessary—such an economic system will have far more
ability to make possible any necessary change in the earth’s climate.
That is the kind of economic system we could reasonably expect to have
in coming generations, if it is not prevented from coming into existence
by policies hostile to economic progress, notably those urged by Sir
Nicholas and the environmental movement.
What Sir Nicholas and the rest of the environmental movement offer is
merely the destruction of much of our existing means of coping with
nature and the aborting of the development of new and additional means.
To the extent that their program is enacted, it will serve to prevent
effectively dealing with global warming if that should ever actually be
necessary.
A major word of caution is necessary here. The above discussion implies
that the use of modern technology to control climate is infinitely more
reasonable than the virtually insane policy of attempting to control
climate by means of destroying modern technology. The word of caution is
that in the hands of government, a policy of climate control based on
the use modern technology could be almost as dangerous as the policy of
government climate control by means of the destruction of modern
technology.
In fact, a possible outcome of today’s intellectual chaos on the
subjects of environment and government is a combination of major
destruction of our economic system resulting from policies based on
hostility to carbon technology and
climate damage caused by governmental efforts to control climate through
the use of modern technology. It’s not impossible that what we might end
up with is an economic system largely destroyed by environmentalist
policies plus the start of a new ice age resulting from government
efforts to counteract global warming through the use of technologically
inspired counter measures.
The only safe response to global warming, if that in fact is what is
unfolding, or to global freezing, when that develops, as it inevitably
will, is the maximum degree of individual freedom. (For elaboration and
proof of this proposition, see
Capitalism, pp. 88-90.)
Any serious consideration of the proposals made in the
Stern Review for radically
reducing carbon technology and the accompanying calls for immediacy in
enacting them makes clear in a further way how utterly impractical the
environmentalist program for controlling global warming actually is. The
fundamental impracticality of the program, of course, lies in its
utterly destructive character. But in addition to that, the fact that
people are not prepared easily or quickly to make a massive sacrifice of
their self-interests dooms the enactment of the program. Even if, in
utter contradiction of the truth, the program were sound, it would
simply not be possible to enact it in time to satisfy the
environmentalists that the level of carbon buildup they fear will not
occur. In other words, the world is quickly moving past the window of
opportunity for enacting the environmentalists’ program for controlling
global warming. (Concerning this point, see pp. xi-xii of the
Executive Summary,
especially Figure 3 on p. xii.) The implication is that either they will
have to find another issue or different means for addressing the issue.
The only different means, however, are technological in character.
Environmentalism thus stands a very strong chance of ultimately
reverting to the more traditional socialism of massive government
construction and engineering projects. It’s future may well lie with
what is coming to be called
“geo-engineering.”
We shall see.
This article is copyright © 2006, by George Reisman. Permission is
hereby granted to reproduce and distribute it electronically and in
print, other than as part of a book and provided that mention of the
author’s web site
www.capitalism.net
is included.
(Email notification
is requested.)
All other rights reserved. George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics
(Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) and is Pepperdine University
Professor Emeritus of Economics.
Return to Top of
Page