THE INTELLECTUAL VOICE OF CAPITALISM ON THE INTERNET
The Jefferson School of Philosophy, Economics, and Psychology

Literature and Lectures by Edith Packer, George Reisman, and Others

Reisman's Blog

Reisman's Essays and News Commentaries

Library of Liberty

The Jefferson School Mission Statement

Home

Join our mailing list  E-mail us TJS Contact Information and Customer Policies TJS Accepts Credit Cards View Cart

 
Reisman's Program of Self-Education in the Economic Theory and Political Philosophy of Capitalism 2.0, on CDs, in mp3 format.


CAPITALISM:
A Treatise on Economics

by
George Reisman


The Clearest and Most Comprehensive Contemporary Defense of the Capitalist Economic System Available

Click on image or description above to bring up the complete text in pdf.


Literature and Lectures by Edith Packer, George Reisman, and Others



Noble Vision, a novel by Genevieve LaGreca


Now available in paperback
 

  • Ludwig von Mises's Human Action in pdf, courtesy of Bettina Bien Greaves and Laissez-Faire Books

In Association with Amazon.com

An Important Message concerning ordering.

 

A Simple Super-Weapon Against Middle-East Terrorism: Economic Freedom for the U.S. Energy Industry*

By

George Reisman**

Middle-Eastern terrorism rests on a foundation of financial support in the form of revenues derived from the sale of oil by the members of the OPEC cartel. Sometimes, as in the case of Iraq and Libya, the connection is simple and direct—oil revenues go straight to terrorist governments, either because the terrorist government itself owns the oil deposits or because it collects taxes based on oil revenues. Such revenues are then used to finance terrorist operations.

In other cases, such as Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates, the connection is indirect and somewhat less simple. Here, as a minimum, the enrichment of the region, based on the fact that it possesses oil which it sells in the world market, makes possible a demand for goods and services in the region that would otherwise not exist. For example, the fortune inherited by Osama Bin Laden was in the construction industry. The Bin Laden construction firm is reportedly the largest construction firm in Saudi Arabia. Saudi Arabia’s ability to support a construction industry, and to make a construction firm rich, rests on the revenue it derives from oil, which is then used in part to finance construction projects. The portion of this wealth inherited by Osama Bin Laden finances terrorism.

But Bin Laden’s activities are by no means limited to his own personal funds. He regularly receives funds, reportedly in the guise of charitable contributions, from large numbers of Arabs whose wealth and income rests on a direct or indirect connection to oil, and who would lack the ability to make those contributions, or at least contributions as large as they now do, if their wealth and income were smaller.

Thus, in the ways just described, the oil revenues received by OPEC are the direct or indirect financial foundation of Middle-East terrorism. To the extent that those revenues could be reduced, given the region’s prevailing cultural backwardness and lack of ability to generate significant wealth through industrialization, all wealth and income in the region would be reduced and thus, so too, would be its ability to support terrorism.

It clearly follows that the key to choking off the funds that finance terrorism is to reduce as far as possible the funds now flowing to OPEC. Based on an annual production by OPEC of about eleven billion barrels of oil, every dollar by which the average annual price of a barrel of oil can be made to fall means approximately eleven billion dollars a year less going to OPEC and thus correspondingly less money directly or indirectly available with which to finance terrorism.

The means are readily available to bring about at least a ten dollar per barrel reduction in the price of oil and probably a twenty dollar or more reduction. What makes possible the potential for such large declines in a relatively short period of time is the very same characteristic of the demand for oil that leads to spikes in its price when its production is cut by just a few percent, namely, the so-called inelasticity of the demand for oil. This is the fact that to reduce the quantity of oil demanded by a relatively small amount, or to increase it by a relatively small amount, substantially larger changes in price are required. Thus, in the 1970s, for example, to reduce the quantity of oil demanded by a few percent, a more than doubling of the price of oil was required. In the 1980s, the price of oil fell by about two thirds in response to relatively modest increases in the supply of oil. Such a large decrease in price was required in order for the market to be able to absorb the additional supply of oil that then became available.

Today, it is possible once again to bring about a dramatic fall in the price of oil, indeed, one even larger than occurred in the 1980s.  And it could begin right away. All that is necessary is to abolish the U.S. government’s restrictions on domestic energy production inspired by the environmentalist movement.

Consider the potential for increasing the supply of oil by opening up to the drilling for oil both the whole of the continental shelf of the United States and all of the vast so-called wildlife preserves and wilderness areas in Alaska and in all of the rest of the country. Certainly, these sources could soon very easily increase the world’s supply of oil by the few percent needed to make the price of oil plunge. And to the extent that OPEC sought to prevent a fall in price by equivalently curtailing its own production, it would be deprived of the full amount of the revenues it had earned on that production. In addition, any  maintenance of the high price by OPEC would serve only to put revenues and profits that it had been earning into the pockets of its American competitors, who would thereby have the financial means as well as the incentive for further expansion at OPEC’s expense.

Abolishing our restrictions on coal and natural gas production and on atomic power would further compound OPEC’s problems. This is because any expansion in the supply of these competing sources of energy and fall in their price serves to reduce the quantity of oil demanded at any given price of oil. The result is that in the face of a fall in the demand for oil, any given production of oil can be sold only at a lower price than would otherwise be possible. In other words, the price of oil would fall not only because of an increase in its supply but also because of the decrease in the demand for oil resulting from the increase in the supply of coal, natural gas, and atomic power. There would be a larger supply of energy in general and a fall in the price of energy in general.

In an environment of economic freedom for energy production in the United States, OPEC would lose all incentive to maintain the price of oil at anywhere near its present level by reducing the quantity of oil it produced. This is because it would then have to reduce its production by an amount equal not only to the expansion of oil production in the United States but also to the reduction in the quantity of oil demanded because of  the increase in the supply and fall in price of competing sources of energy. The magnitude of reduction in its production of oil that would be required to offset all of this expansion would be too great to make the reduction worthwhile to OPEC.

Indeed, it is implicit that had the United States pursued a policy of economic freedom with respect to energy production over the last thirty years, the conditions for OPEC’s success as a cartel would never have been present in the first place, and the accumulation of vast funds capable of supporting terrorism would never have been able to occur. Every barrel of oil that the environmentalists have succeeded in getting the U.S. government not to allow to be produced, every ton of coal that they have prevented from being mined, every atomic power plant whose construction they have stopped, has served to make oil scarcer and more expensive and correspondingly to enrich OPEC and increase the funds available for the support of terrorism.

Today, after thousands of needless deaths and major destruction of property of symbolic as well as economic value, it is not only the so-called moderate Arab governments who have a choice to make. The supporters of environmentalism here in the United States must also choose. Which do they value more: indulging their exaggerated fear of oil spills on beaches and their boundless desire for nature untouched by man, or the lives and property of innocent victims of terrorism and, as now seems likely, the lives of hundreds and possibly thousands of young servicemen and women and the potentially enormous economic costs of a war?

True enough, decades of policies serving to enrich the supporters of terrorism have made it impossible for a policy of freedom for energy production in the United States all by itself to now strip the terrorists of financial support. But it would certainly very substantially help in reducing such support. And it would show up in lives and property saved. The environmentalists must choose.

***

Afterword: Normally, economic freedom should not be thought of as a means of impoverishing anyone or as any kind of weapon. Its normal character is one of universal enrichment. It becomes a means of impoverishment and a weapon in the present case only because of the presence of the combination of two special circumstances. First, the prior existence of extensive monopoly privilege, which we have created for OPEC to the extent that our laws and regulations prohibit the competition of American energy producers. Second, the fact that the extremely backward culture of the Arab world—its religious fanaticism and accompanying disdain for individual rights and freedom—serves to prevent successful adaptation to changed conditions and the earning of substantial wealth not based on monopoly privilege.

In contrast, when advances take place within the Western world, such as the automobile displacing the horse and buggy, the effect is to benefit even those who initially are displaced. Those displaced find new jobs and once they have acquired levels of skill and ability in their new occupations comparable to those they had in the jobs they lost, benefit in their capacity as consumers from the advance that initially caused their loss. In the Western world, even those who fall from the highest economic positions can ultimately come out ahead in the position merely of an average worker, thanks to continued economic progress. But not so in a culture in which if one does not have the benefit of monopoly privilege applied to the accident of sitting atop a large quantity of an important natural resource, one is rendered incapable of having much of anything.


*Copyright © 2001 by George Reisman. All rights reserved.

**George Reisman, Ph.D., is professor of Economics at Pepperdine University’s Graziadio School of Business and Management and is the author of Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics (Ottawa, Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996). 

  Return to Top of Page